全文获取类型
收费全文 | 752篇 |
免费 | 0篇 |
专业分类
752篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 7篇 |
2019年 | 17篇 |
2018年 | 13篇 |
2017年 | 17篇 |
2016年 | 16篇 |
2015年 | 15篇 |
2013年 | 134篇 |
2011年 | 9篇 |
2010年 | 7篇 |
2009年 | 10篇 |
2008年 | 7篇 |
2007年 | 8篇 |
2006年 | 8篇 |
2005年 | 16篇 |
2004年 | 14篇 |
2003年 | 9篇 |
2000年 | 10篇 |
1999年 | 9篇 |
1998年 | 7篇 |
1997年 | 11篇 |
1996年 | 20篇 |
1995年 | 6篇 |
1994年 | 16篇 |
1993年 | 9篇 |
1992年 | 11篇 |
1991年 | 24篇 |
1990年 | 9篇 |
1989年 | 17篇 |
1988年 | 9篇 |
1987年 | 17篇 |
1986年 | 18篇 |
1985年 | 22篇 |
1984年 | 12篇 |
1983年 | 9篇 |
1982年 | 7篇 |
1981年 | 10篇 |
1980年 | 13篇 |
1979年 | 10篇 |
1978年 | 10篇 |
1977年 | 13篇 |
1976年 | 12篇 |
1975年 | 7篇 |
1974年 | 16篇 |
1973年 | 10篇 |
1972年 | 17篇 |
1971年 | 17篇 |
1970年 | 10篇 |
1969年 | 10篇 |
1968年 | 9篇 |
1967年 | 8篇 |
排序方式: 共有752条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
611.
In this article we consider a stochastic model for two products which have a single-period inventory structure and which can be used as substitutes for each other should the need arise. Substitution will occur with probability one, but at perhaps a different revenue level. We prove that the expected profit function is concave, allowing us to find optimal stocking levels for the two products. We compare optimum inventory levels for the case of single substitution with that where there is no substitution. It is demonstrated for the case of single substitution that total optimum order quantities can actually increase or decrease with the substitution revenue. 相似文献
612.
613.
614.
615.
616.
This paper considers a two-agent scheduling problem with linear resource-dependent processing times, in which each agent has a set of jobs that compete with that of the other agent for the use of a common processing machine, and each agent aims to minimize the weighted number of its tardy jobs. To meet the due date requirements of the jobs of the two agents, additional amounts of a common resource, which may be in discrete or continuous quantities, can be allocated to the processing of the jobs to compress their processing durations. The actual processing time of a job is a linear function of the amount of the resource allocated to it. The objective is to determine the optimal job sequence and resource allocation strategy so as to minimize the weighted number of tardy jobs of one agent, while keeping the weighted number of tardy jobs of the other agent, and the total resource consumption cost within their respective predetermined limits. It is shown that the problem is -hard in the ordinary sense, and there does not exist a polynomial-time approximation algorithm with performance ratio unless ; however it admits a relaxed fully polynomial time approximation scheme. A proximal bundle algorithm based on Lagrangian relaxation is also presented to solve the problem approximately. To speed up convergence and produce sharp bounds, enhancement strategies including the design of a Tabu search algorithm and integration of a Lagrangian recovery heuristic into the algorithm are devised. Extensive numerical studies are conducted to assess the effectiveness and efficiency of the proposed algorithms. 相似文献
617.
Ross A. Kennedy 《战略研究杂志》2013,36(7):1058-1070
The books under review here, by Robert F. Hannigan, John A. Thompson, Trygve Throntveit, and Adam Tooze, offer an interpretation of Wilsonian internationalism and what happened to it in the 1920s. For Tooze and Hannigan, Wilsonianism was primarily a project to attain American predominance in the world. For Throntveit, Wilsonian internationalism constituted a pragmatic yet radical effort to end competitive power politics. Thompson disagrees with these arguments and asserts that the key to understanding US policy lay in how US leaders conceptualized American power. Thompson’s interpretation is especially compelling in explaining why the United States failed to engage itself more assertively in international affairs in the 1920s – a failure Tooze suggests undermined the viability of the postwar international system. 相似文献
618.
Nicholas A Lambert 《战略研究杂志》2013,36(2):272-297
The Fisher naval revolution of 1904–10 represented a deliberate attempt to achieve defense transformation to bolster Britain's pretensions to global naval supremacy. The vision called for smaller, more capable forces to do the work of larger, more expensive conventional formations. It consisted of three main elements. First, the replacement of the traditional station fleet system for protecting overseas interests by rapid deployment forces comprised of battlecruisers that could be ‘maneuvered’ by wireless to combat specific enemy threats. Second, at home, instead of a sea control strategy based upon a superior battle-fleet, a sea denial strategy based on flotilla defense commanded and controlled from London via wireless. The third element of the Fisher revolution depended upon ‘plunging’, or shaping and directing technological change through a special relationship with armaments firms. A sophisticated information-communications network was integral to the revolution. 相似文献
619.
A recent article, ‘Rage Against the Machines’, does a disservice to the debate over what explains counterinsurgency (COIN) success. While it establishes a negative correlation between the diffusion of military mechanization in the state system and COIN success, its theoretical argument does not hold up under close scrutiny and its micro-case comparison of two units in Iraq during 2003–2004 ignores obvious counter-examples and factors that influence COIN success, such as leadership. A deeper inquiry would have revealed that there is much more to COIN success than simply not having access to vehicles. 相似文献
620.
David A. Patten 《Small Wars & Insurgencies》2013,24(5):879-906
Taking insurgency sponsorship as an instrument states have available for achieving foreign policy objectives, I consider how state-sponsors could best manipulate their support to maximize control of the proxy group. Building on research that models the state-sponsor–insurgent relationship using a principal–agent framework, I identify two key vulnerabilities to which the state-sponsor is exposed: adverse selection and agency slack. As an original contribution to the literature on state-sponsorship of insurgency, I articulate reasons why certain forms of support would be most conducive to overcoming these problems and illustrate how South Africa and Iran used those kinds of support to influence the behavior of their proxies, RENAMO and Hezbollah. Additionally, I consider how this principal–agent analysis of insurgency sponsorship also could apply when the principal is an international terrorist organization such as al Qaeda. Finally, I address the relevance of these ideas to two contemporary conflicts taking place in Syria and the Congo. 相似文献