全文获取类型
收费全文 | 897篇 |
免费 | 0篇 |
专业分类
897篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 10篇 |
2019年 | 18篇 |
2018年 | 8篇 |
2017年 | 19篇 |
2016年 | 17篇 |
2015年 | 16篇 |
2014年 | 18篇 |
2013年 | 161篇 |
2012年 | 8篇 |
2010年 | 9篇 |
2009年 | 14篇 |
2007年 | 16篇 |
2006年 | 9篇 |
2005年 | 10篇 |
2004年 | 13篇 |
2003年 | 11篇 |
2002年 | 14篇 |
2000年 | 8篇 |
1999年 | 9篇 |
1998年 | 17篇 |
1997年 | 14篇 |
1996年 | 13篇 |
1995年 | 7篇 |
1994年 | 21篇 |
1993年 | 23篇 |
1992年 | 15篇 |
1991年 | 21篇 |
1990年 | 15篇 |
1989年 | 28篇 |
1988年 | 25篇 |
1987年 | 22篇 |
1986年 | 26篇 |
1985年 | 19篇 |
1984年 | 11篇 |
1983年 | 10篇 |
1982年 | 15篇 |
1981年 | 14篇 |
1980年 | 11篇 |
1979年 | 16篇 |
1978年 | 18篇 |
1977年 | 7篇 |
1976年 | 11篇 |
1975年 | 9篇 |
1974年 | 15篇 |
1973年 | 10篇 |
1972年 | 12篇 |
1971年 | 11篇 |
1970年 | 14篇 |
1969年 | 10篇 |
1967年 | 10篇 |
排序方式: 共有897条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
891.
James R. Jackson 《海军后勤学研究》1967,14(1):23-41
Certain zero-sum games are examined in which an individual player is opposed by a two-man team. The members of the team have identical interests, but must act separately during play. Most of the paper is devoted to instances in which one teammate has an opportunity to communicate to the other about their mutual opponent's strategy; but he may only be able to transmit a limited amount of information and his choice of a “message” may affect the payoff. The team must thus make economically efficient use of a limited communication opportunity. The present paper treats a variety of models, all of which are formulated as rectangular (matrix) games. Related models, some of which cannot be so formulated either because of restrictions on the team's opportunities to use mixed strategies or because they are non-zero-sum games, will be treated in another paper. 相似文献
892.
893.
Recent supply‐chain models that study competition among capacity‐constrained producers omit the possibility of producers strategically setting wholesale prices to create uncertainty with regards to (i.e., to obfuscate) their production capacities. To shed some light on this possibility, we study strategic obfuscation in a supply‐chain model comprised of two competing producers and a retailer, where one of the producers faces a privately‐known capacity constraint. We show that capacity obfuscation can strictly increase the obfuscating producer's profit, therefore, presenting a clear incentive for such practices. Moreover, we identify conditions under which both producers' profits increase. In effect, obfuscation enables producers to tacitly collude and charge higher wholesale prices by moderating competition between producers. The retailer, in contrast, suffers a loss in profit, raises retail prices, while overall channel profits decrease. We show that the extent of capacity obfuscation is limited by its cost and by a strategic retailer's incentive to facilitate a deterrence. © 2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Naval Research Logistics 61: 244–267, 2014 相似文献
894.
895.
J. Atsu Amegashie 《Defence and Peace Economics》2014,25(4):381-400
I study a two-period model of conflict with two combatants and a third party who is an ally of one of the combatants. The third party is fully informed about the type of her ally but not about the type of her ally’s enemy. In a signaling game, I find that if the third party is unable to give a sufficiently high assistance to her ally, then there exists a unique separating equilibrium in which the third party’s expected intervention causes her ally’s enemy to exert more effort than in the absence of third-party intervention; this worsens the conflict. 相似文献
896.
Stephen J. Cimbala 《Defense & Security Analysis》2014,30(1):29-43
US nuclear deterrence and arms control policy may be moving, by design and by inadvertence, toward a posture of strategic “defensivism”. Strategic “defensivism” emphasizes the overlapping and reinforcing impact of: (1) reductions in US, Russian and possibly other strategic nuclear forces, possibly down to the level of “minimum deterrence,” (2) deployment of improved strategic and/or theater antimissile defenses for the US, NATO allies and other partners; and (3) additional reliance on conventional military forces for some missions hitherto preferentially assigned to nuclear weapons. This article deals with the first two of these aspects only: the interaction between missile defenses and offensive force reductions in US–Russian strategy and policy. The findings are that stable deterrence as between the USA and Russia is possible at lower than New Strategic Arms Reduction Treaty levels, but reductions below 1000 deployed long-range weapons for each state, toward a true minimum deterrent posture, will require multilateral as opposed to bilateral coordination of arms limitations. Missile defenses might provide some denial capability against light attacks by states with small arsenals, but they still fall short of meaningful damage limitation as between powers capable of massive nuclear strikes. 相似文献
897.
GORDON JE 《Military review》1949,28(12):27; passim